Ethical Circuit of Value
Excerpts from https://lists.thing.net/pipermail/idc/2008-February/003139.html.
Contents
Description
Adam Arvidsson introduces the third circuit of value:
"Brands can be understood to embody a third important form of capital
in the knowledge economy, along with material capital and knowledge
capital. Like knowledge capital (IPs) they work to establish a
monopoly rent from a resource that is essentially socially produced.
Unlike IPs this resource mainly consists in accumulated affect and
sociality. (The value of a brand depends on a mass of people
maintaining a relatively stable pattern of affectivity around it, a
brand is in this sense something a kin to, almost , a loosely knitted
community, or maybe a community of weak ties) This way brands are a
form of ethical capital: they build on the ability and desire of free
(that is not entirely commanded) actors to create community, in the
absence of given hierarchies or monetary obligations (cf.
Aristoteles’ etikos).
Brands thus establish a third circuit of value (M-C-M’) that is
central to informational capitalism.
The first, material, circuit of value is the classic one described by Marx, value is extracted by submitting commanded labor to discipline. In this situation the means of production are monopolized by capital and labor time can work as an (approximate) measure that allows the systematic abstraction of concrete labor into abstract value.
The second circuit is that of knowledge capital. This builds in part on the direct command over salaried labor and the ‘classic’ abstraction of surplus value. To an increasing extent however it builds on the ability to appropriate socially produced resources that are not directly ‘owned’ by capital and that, consequently cannot be directly commanded. This can be the results of state sponsored investments in research and development, it can be the synergic productivity of social interaction among knowledge workers, research institutions and knowledge intensive firms (learning regions, creative cities) and increasingly it is a matter of the direct appropriation of knowledge and innovation generated in the everyday interaction among ordinary consumers (user- led innovation systems, crowdsourcing, etc.).
Brands constitute a third circuit that appropriates and commodifies the ethical practice of ordinary consumers: their ability and desire to build community.
This ethical practice is itself the dialectical result of the (virtual) completion of the capitalist subsumption of the social. That process has produced two important outcomes.
First, the diffusion of consumer goods, media culture and ultimately networked ICTs has greatly enhanced the ability of ordinary people to produce a symbolic and affective – ethical- framework for life. What Marx has called ‘General Intellect’ has thus come at the disposition of everybody, as mass intellectuality.
Second, the subsumption of the social has shattered traditional life forms and generated a widespread isolation and alienation. Networked ICTs enable people to overcome this condition by generating new forms of sociality. Indeed as new media scholars like Danah Boyd and Jean Luis Prada (among others) have argued it is mainly the desire for sociality that motivates the use of social media. The source of brand value is thus the immanent ethical productivity of the social, its new and empowered ability and desire to produce community." (https://lists.thing.net/pipermail/idc/2008-February/003139.html)
Discussion
The Value of Ethical Capital
Adam Arvidsson:
"What creates these ethical values? They are not the direct results of investments in labor time. You can work as much as you want on your music and style, that, in itself will not make you a rock star. Rather, suddenly something happens and then, you’ve made it. What determines your value are the quality and quantity of affect (attention) that you have been able to accumulate. The relation between the productive time invested in a project and the mass affect that it is able to attract is non-linear, or viral, to use a popular marketing term.[2] Models could be found in contemporary mathematical theories of network dynamics, and perhaps in Gabriel Tarde’s theories of the role of public sentiment.[3] Indeed, the logical relation between value and labor is rather the reverse of that usually associated with the capitalist economy. Once you have a sufficiently attractive brand, you will attract an abundance of free labor as well as other resources. Linux has no problems recruiting new programmers: people want to work for them for free; people pay to use brands in their everyday life and thus freely co-produce their ethical value through their constructive consumer practices. On financial markets, capital flows to the most attractive brands. More means more in this case, if you have accumulated a significant stock of ethical capital, people will freely give you their time and further attention, or, on financial markets, their capital.
The logic behind ethical capital is political rather than economic.
Or better it pertains to what Weber saw as the charismatic,
irrational side of politics. If you, or your brand, can mobilize the
affective energies of the polis, its members will freely put their
resources at your disposition. (Fight for your cause; work for you;
vote for you; give to you of their hospitality- indeed, as Weber
claimed, peaceful charismatic leaders mainly live off donations from
the community that they have created[4]). The source of this valuable
charisma is, as in Weber’s classic analysis, the ability to create
community. (By contrast the economic logic of value would be based on
the ability to command labor (as in the oikos) and thus measure its
contribution in terms of labor time.) The predominance of brand
value, reputation, ‘ethical capital’, corporate ethics and similar
entities as elements to the immeasurable intangible values that are
increasingly important to contemporary capitalism is an empirical
indication of the fact that this political logic of value is becoming
increasingly influential in informational capitalism.
Today such political values can only be translated into one abstract
equivalent, monetary exchange value. The question is however, can
such political values be made tradable in other ways; and how, in
that case, would such a system look like?"
(https://lists.thing.net/pipermail/idc/2008-February/003139.html)
Towards a general exchange of esteem
Adam Arvidsson:
"One point of departure could be Brennan & Pettit’s idea of an ‘economy of esteem’. Coming from a background of academic economics, they show how that discipline has continuously devalued the importance of honor and esteem (central to its precursors like Smith and Hume) in favor of a monetary economy of commodities. Yet, they argue the economy of esteem is still at work as a powerful force in everyday life, in particular within academia (from which most of their examples derive). The point of the ‘economy of esteem’ is that esteem is a scarce good conferred on an actor by the public in relation to his or her performance in some area. This means that even though the actor might be motivated to perform well in an area in the prospect of achieving esteem, performance is never directly exchanged for esteem. There are two reasons for this. One, because esteem is subjectively and voluntarily conferred at the actor in question: there is no point at which he or she (or they) can righteously claim esteem from the public. And, two, because doing so, claiming esteem, goes against the principle that the charismatic actor must appear not to act directly in order to increase his or her charisma. A brand like Nike can acquire esteem if it donates an empty building wall in Berlin for young people to express themselves on. It will loose esteem in so far as the strategic intentions behind this ‘gift’ become apparent and talked about. So esteem should not, as Brennan& Pettit do, be understood as something that is directly exchanged for performance. [5] Since the relation between esteem and performance is not subject to rational calculation- it is rather an unpredictable, non-linear relation, there is no possibility for any rational exchange. Rather the relation between esteem and performance should be understood along the lines of a gift economy. If I give this performance to the community, I can expect to receive roughly that amount of esteem. But there is no legitimate way I can complain, take action or withdraw my performance if I receive less esteem than I had expected. But can esteem in one community be exchanged for esteem in another?
Traditional systems of honor and esteem have worked in close-knit
communities. Scaling them towards the contemporary information
economy will necessarily entail making esteem transferable between
different communities with different value standards. What is needed
to accomplish this is a general medium of exchange, which like
monetary exchange value can guarantee the transferability to values.
Such a medium would be different from traditional currencies however:
The amount of esteem an actor can acquire thus has a non-linear
relation to his or her measurable performance. This is mainly because
esteem is a multifaceted affective quality that originates in
subjective judgment that cannot be entirely rationalized: it is an
irrational quality in the Weberian sense of that term. So any
objective measure of esteem- the first precondition for making it
tradable- could not depart from some common measurable standard (like
labor time)- but would had to consist in an aggregation of a
multitude of subjective judgments. It would be a sort of bottom-up
currency, where values are defined by the continuous input of public
ratings.
Two factors speak for the possibility for the emergence of such
general media of exchange of esteem. One factor is the increasing
transparency and visibility of social action. The flip-side to
increasing surveillance is in this sense the possibility for a new
ethics: everything you do will be potentially visible to everyone.
One’s public person could thus form a common point of reference that
unites estimates of esteem from different communities. Personality
becomes a generalized medium of communication. The second factor is
the socialization of the means of organization in networked ICTs. The
establishment of representative money from the Sumer and onwards has
been contingent on the administrative capacity of the state apparatus
controlling the money supply. Now such administrative capacity is at
the hands of virtually everyone, and consequently we already see the
emergence of alternative currencies like LETS or Open Money. Some of
these currencies could be esteem-based. Indeed the world’s second
largest currency, air-miles, already is.[6] Essentially air-miles is
a measure of the affective appreciation that an airline has of you as
loyal customer, and they can be traded for a wide range of gifts:
free trips, upgrades, car rentals etc. (Again air-miles do not have
an objective exchange value, strictly speaking, since their relation
to possible gifts is subjectively and variably determined by the
airline itself. Relationship should rather be understood as that of a
stable gift economy. I give my loyalty to the airline. I can
reasonably expect the airline to give me a certain kind of gifts in
return.) Slashdot Karma is another one, quantifying the esteem you
have accumulated by contributing to various blogs, by systematically
integrating a multitude of subjective ratings of your performance."
(https://lists.thing.net/pipermail/idc/2008-February/003139.html)
References
See original article at https://lists.thing.net/pipermail/idc/2008-February/003139.html